14 research outputs found

    The ecology of technology : the co-evolution of technology and organization

    Get PDF
    In this day and age, arguing that technology is a powerful force that drives many economic processes is like preaching to the choir. Nevertheless, despite the widespread realization of the important role of technology in our modern day society, an intimate understanding of the process of technological change is still lacking. This study seeks to provide more insight into the concept of technological change by characterizing it as a socio-cultural evolutionary process of variation, selection and retention. According to this logic, variety (or novelty) is created by (random or non-random) mutations (i.e., organizations and individuals that (re-) combine existing components in novel ways). This variety is subsequently selected out by the stakeholders in the environment, such as individuals, organizations, and institutions. In other words, the variety is then retained in the structural characteristics of the environment, commonly referred to as organizational routines and technological paradigms. Finally, these structural characteristics subsequently provide the context in/from which new mutations (or variations) are created. From there, the cycle can be repeated. Because, nowadays, technology is mostly developed in an organizational context, the appropriate place to study technology and technological change is in the context of organization science, which is an academic discipline that studies all facets of organization. Even though technology deserves a central role in any organization theory, technology has not yet penetrated fully the domain of organization science. The only domain in which technology has a central role is within evolutionary economics, a school of economic thought that was influenced by evolutionary biology. Even though evolutionary economics has surely added much to our understanding of the process of technological change, in our view, this school of thought mainly concentrates its attention on idiosyncratic accounts of variety creation and their subsequent selection by the environment. Much less attention has been attributed to how the selection environment (or the structural characteristics thereof) determines the variety creation. Consequently, insights from organizational ecology, which has its center of gravity at the selection environment, can add value over and above the ones originating from evolutionary economics. The key source of inspiration of organizational ecology is bioecology, which makes it evolutionary economics’ counterpart in sociology. In this study, we therefore seek to close the evolutionary circle by developing a structural or ecological perspective of technological change. After all, holding both links between variety and selection in focus at the same time (i.e., how variety is selected by the environment, and how the selection environment facilitates and constrains the creation of variety) provides for a truly evolutionary model of technological change. Accordingly, we define our research objective as follows: Research objective: To develop an ecology of technology in organization science. Because this objective is rather vague and abstract, we formulate several research questions to provide more direction in our quest to fulfill our objective. We formulate our first research question as follows. Research question 1: What is the importance of biotechnology? Providing an answer to this research question is the subject of Chapter 2. As a means of introducing biotechnology, we first describe biotechnology’s central dogma (i.e., DNA as the building block of life). Moreover, we provide a timeline to get a certain feel of the history and evolution of biotechnology, and list numerous socio-economic trends to get an idea of the importance of biotechnology in society. These trends clearly illustrate that biotechnology drives important social and economic events. Next, we evaluate biotechnology’s position in the overall technological landscape. Our main finding is that, despite its sharply increasing societal and economic importance, biotechnology still has not yet conquered a place in the technological core of our society. Reviewing the developments within synthetic biology (in this domain, complex systems are designed by (re-)combining DNA into biological parts that represent biological functions and, as such, is the domain where all aspects of biotechnology come together), it becomes clear that biotechnology as a whole is not yet in the growth stage of technological convergence that is characterized by a stable configuration of component technologies (i.e., a dominant design). Moreover, on the basis of the future expectations of experts, we conclude that biotechnology is a strategic technology that is nowhere near its peak influence, and that we can expect the importance to increase even further over the coming years. Obviously, whether biotechnology can deliver on its promise and materialize the expectations of insiders is not certain. Even when biotechnology delivers on only a small part of the promise, though, its impact will already be gigantic. For example, consider the fact that, in a 2007 interview, Craig Venter – who is one of the most well-renowned biotechnologists today – said that, in 20 years time, synthetic genomics is going to become the standard for making anything (Aldhous, 2007). So, in conclusion, biotechnology is a technology that is still emerging and does yet not display a stable and predictable pattern of growth that characterizes mature (i.e., non-emerging) technologies. Our next research question thus is as follows. Research question 2: How to study the growth of an emerging technology? In Chapter 3, on the basis of ecological insights and principles, we develop a structural or systemic view towards technology, and hereby take into explicit account the embedded nature of technology. That is, we propose that it adds value to view technology as a system composed of a set of interdependent components (or subsystems). More specifically, by relying on density dependence theory from organizational ecology, we effectively develop a multilevel framework that can be used to empirically study emerging technologies. Moreover, we employ the concept of the technological niche from organizational ecology, with its associated dimensions of crowding (associated with processes of competition) and status (associated with processes of legitimation), and add diversity as a key dimension. Through sophisticated multivariate analysis of biotechnology patents from the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO), we validate this model, which we label the ‘ecology of technology’. However, we also discover some anomalies, which point to the limitations of our model, the most important being its rather static nature. Because emerging technologies are characterized by fluid patterns of growth, a static model is a severe misrepresentation of the evolution of emerging technologies. Our next research question naturally follows from this. Research question 3: How to study the evolution of an emerging technology? On the basis of insights from evolutionary economics, Chapter 4 distinguishes between two stages of technological development, namely the stages of divergence and convergence (that connect nicely with the seed and growth stage of life cycle theory). The focal element is what is generally referred to as the deep structure (in the context of technology also commonly referred to as a dominant design) that facilitates cumulative changes by reducing uncertainty and enabling specialization and integration through standardization. The stage of divergence is characterized by the absence of a deep structure, while the stage of convergence is characterized by its presence. So, in the latter stage, there is a relatively stable configuration of the system’s component technologies that results in relatively stable and predictable patterns of growth. On the basis of these insights, we adapt our multi-level model to identify these different stages of development at the component level. More specifically, if there is a mutualistic relationship between a component and the system (i.e., if system density contributes positively to component entry), the component is argued to have a dominant design. As we are dealing with an emerging technology, our main interest lies in the transition from the initial seed stage of technological divergence (i.e., the absence of a deep structure) to a growth stage of technological convergence (i.e., the existence of a deep structure), or the creation of a deep structure. This means that we do not take into account the revolutionary transition from a stage of convergence into divergence (i.e., the maturity and decline stage in life cycle theory). Not only do we refine our predictions regarding the effects of our existing dimensions (i.e., multilevel density dependence, crowding, status, and focal diversity), but, by further taking into account the lineage of technology, we refine our dimension of diversity by adding antecedent and descendant diversity as additional dimensions to the technological niche. This results in an intricate model that can be used to study the growth and evolution of an emerging technology. We demonstrate this by an empirical investigation of biotechnology patents from the USPTO and hereby provide further support for our ‘ecology of technology’. In the light of our research objective, before we answer the question of what the precise consequences are for organizations, we ask ourselves how we can effectively integrate our findings at the organizational level of analysis. We thus formulate our next research question accordingly. Research question 4: How can we integrate technology into the theory of the organization specifictechnological niche? In Chapter 5, we use a process of logical formalization to represent the theory of the organization-specific technological niche in a formal logical language. The reason for doing so is threefold. First, this forces us to explicate all underlying assumptions and to remove any inconsistencies to make the argument logically sound. Second, this requires us to supplement the theory so that it is complete, without missing elements. Third and finally, it results in a logically sound and complete theory fragment ready for extension by integrating the insights from the study of the evolution of technology. We choose nonmonotonic logic as the language in which we represent our arguments because nonmonotonic logic is better suited for theory building, and this connects better to the current wave of formalization in non-monotonic logic in organizational ecology. On the basis of this analysis, we already make two important theoretical extensions. First, by distinguishing between crowding in technological and market space, we tie technological crowding to both competition and legitimation. To be precise, technological crowding results in competition mainly if the crowding organization is a competitor of the focal organization. Second, uncertainty mediates the relationship between the perceived and actual technological quality of the organization. More specifically, under uncertainty, the actual quality of an organization’s technology cannot be readily observed so that resource controllers have to rely on status (i.e., historic technological quality) instead. With this formalized, logically sound and complete theory fragment in hand, we can turn to the question of the organizational consequences. We thus pose our next research question as follows. Research question 5: What are the consequences of integrating several technological insights into thetheory of the organization-specific technological niche? In Chapter 6, we integrate four technological insights from Chapters 3 and 4 into our formalized theory fragment from the previous chapter. These insights are: (1) multiple technological domains exist that have (2) different stages of development, (3) different levels of uncertainty, and (4) different growth rates. On the basis of these four insights, we extend the theory of the organization-specific technological niche considerably. For crowding, we demonstrate that the effect of crowding is not only conditional upon the identity of the other organization, but also on the stage of technological development. We also add non-crowding to the mix. Regarding the effect of (non-)crowding, in the stage of divergence, multiple competing design configurations exist, and crowding (non-crowding) increases (decreases) the competitiveness of the supported design configuration, having a legitimating (competition) effect. In contrast, in the stage of convergence, crowding (non-crowding) loses its legitimating (competition) function and results in competitive (legitimation) pressure. For status, the most important consequences are that: (1) status is domain dependent, and (2) its effect is dependent upon the stage of technological development (i.e., the effect of status is higher in the stage of divergence). We also add two additional dimensions, which are (1) technological opportunities (that can be represented by the growth rate of the domain), and (2) technological diversity (measured by the distribution of activities over alternative domains). By operationalizing performance as a two-dimensional vector, we suggest that the dimensions of the technological niche are related to different performance measures in distinct temporal relationships. However, even though this theoretical extension is certainly valuable, the subsequent question is whether these extensions hold when subjected to advanced empirical tests. We therefore formulate our next research question as follows. Research question 6: Can we find proof for our extended theory of the organization-specific technological niche? In Chapter 7, we empirically test several of our theoretical extensions of the organization-specific technological niche. Our dependent variable is biotechnology innovation (i.e., the number of biotechnology patents). Through a sophisticated empirical analysis, we find strong support for our extended theory. However, we also encounter some inconsistencies and anomalies. This seems to connect to the fact that processes of competition and legitimation are more appropriately defined at lower levels of analysis (i.e., at the component instead of at the system level). Moreover, due to the dual role of a direct technological tie (i.e., it can have both a competing and a legitimating function) that forms the basis for our measure of status, status is better defined at the component level of analysis. In contrast, biotechnological quality can be aggregated to the system level without losing significance. We thus find strong support for this dimension. Furthermore, we also clearly demonstrate the importance of taking into account the different dimensions of technological diversity (i.e., antecedent, focal, and descendant), with a vital role for antecedent diversity, which logically connects with the notion of absorptive capacity. The subsequent question is what this means for the broader academic debate regarding the (co-)evolution of technology and organization. We formulate our next research question accordingly. Research question 7: What are the implications for the study of the (co-)evolution of technology and organization? In the final chapter of this dissertation, we start by stating the main contribution of this dissertation, which is that we develop a dynamic multilevel model that can be used to empirically study the evolution of an emerging technology. As this model is based on the assumption that technology can effectively be studied as a system composed of an interacting set of components, we pay explicit attention to the embedded nature of technology. Hence, when studying the evolution of technology, it is inappropriate to focus on a single level of analysis and using a multilevel perspective adds value over and above any single level study. That is, technology (e.g., biotechnology) is composed of a set of technological components (e.g., biotechnology’s component technologies) while, at the same time, being embedded in a larger technological system (i.e., technological landscape). It is precisely this multilevel nature of technology that gives it the potential to close part of the chasm in the debate between organizational adaptation (i.e., the dominant perspective in evolutionary economics) and environmental selection (i.e., the dominant perspective in organizational ecology). More specifically, by defining technology at different levels of analysis (e.g., invention, component, system, and landscape), it is possible to tie the evolution of technology to the evolution of organization at different levels of analysis (i.e., individual organization, population of organizations, community, and society). This enables studying the evolution of technology and organization in unison, and thus provides the basis for a co-evolutionary model of technology and organization. Employing a multilevel perspective to both technology and organization at the same time, and defining technology and organization as nested hierarchies tied together at multiple levels of analysis, effectively allows an analyzes of how stable configurations travels upwards in this hierarchy. After all, "it is the information about stable configurations […] that guides the process of evolution" (Simon, 1952: 473)

    Meta-analysis of genome-wide association studies of anxiety disorders.

    Get PDF
    Anxiety disorders (ADs), namely generalized AD, panic disorder and phobias, are common, etiologically complex conditions with a partially genetic basis. Despite differing on diagnostic definitions based on clinical presentation, ADs likely represent various expressions of an underlying common diathesis of abnormal regulation of basic threat-response systems. We conducted genome-wide association analyses in nine samples of European ancestry from seven large, independent studies. To identify genetic variants contributing to genetic susceptibility shared across interview-generated DSM-based ADs, we applied two phenotypic approaches: (1) comparisons between categorical AD cases and supernormal controls, and (2) quantitative phenotypic factor scores (FS) derived from a multivariate analysis combining information across the clinical phenotypes. We used logistic and linear regression, respectively, to analyze the association between these phenotypes and genome-wide single nucleotide polymorphisms. Meta-analysis for each phenotype combined results across the nine samples for over 18 000 unrelated individuals. Each meta-analysis identified a different genome-wide significant region, with the following markers showing the strongest association: for case-control contrasts, rs1709393 located in an uncharacterized non-coding RNA locus on chromosomal band 3q12.3 (P=1.65 × 10(-8)); for FS, rs1067327 within CAMKMT encoding the calmodulin-lysine N-methyltransferase on chromosomal band 2p21 (P=2.86 × 10(-9)). Independent replication and further exploration of these findings are needed to more fully understand the role of these variants in risk and expression of ADs.Molecular Psychiatry advance online publication, 12 January 2016; doi:10.1038/mp.2015.197

    The ecology of technology : the co-evolution of technology and organization

    No full text
    In this day and age, arguing that technology is a powerful force that drives many economic processes is like preaching to the choir. Nevertheless, despite the widespread realization of the important role of technology in our modern day society, an intimate understanding of the process of technological change is still lacking. This study seeks to provide more insight into the concept of technological change by characterizing it as a socio-cultural evolutionary process of variation, selection and retention. According to this logic, variety (or novelty) is created by (random or non-random) mutations (i.e., organizations and individuals that (re-) combine existing components in novel ways). This variety is subsequently selected out by the stakeholders in the environment, such as individuals, organizations, and institutions. In other words, the variety is then retained in the structural characteristics of the environment, commonly referred to as organizational routines and technological paradigms. Finally, these structural characteristics subsequently provide the context in/from which new mutations (or variations) are created. From there, the cycle can be repeated. Because, nowadays, technology is mostly developed in an organizational context, the appropriate place to study technology and technological change is in the context of organization science, which is an academic discipline that studies all facets of organization. Even though technology deserves a central role in any organization theory, technology has not yet penetrated fully the domain of organization science. The only domain in which technology has a central role is within evolutionary economics, a school of economic thought that was influenced by evolutionary biology. Even though evolutionary economics has surely added much to our understanding of the process of technological change, in our view, this school of thought mainly concentrates its attention on idiosyncratic accounts of variety creation and their subsequent selection by the environment. Much less attention has been attributed to how the selection environment (or the structural characteristics thereof) determines the variety creation. Consequently, insights from organizational ecology, which has its center of gravity at the selection environment, can add value over and above the ones originating from evolutionary economics. The key source of inspiration of organizational ecology is bioecology, which makes it evolutionary economics’ counterpart in sociology. In this study, we therefore seek to close the evolutionary circle by developing a structural or ecological perspective of technological change. After all, holding both links between variety and selection in focus at the same time (i.e., how variety is selected by the environment, and how the selection environment facilitates and constrains the creation of variety) provides for a truly evolutionary model of technological change. Accordingly, we define our research objective as follows: Research objective: To develop an ecology of technology in organization science. Because this objective is rather vague and abstract, we formulate several research questions to provide more direction in our quest to fulfill our objective. We formulate our first research question as follows. Research question 1: What is the importance of biotechnology? Providing an answer to this research question is the subject of Chapter 2. As a means of introducing biotechnology, we first describe biotechnology’s central dogma (i.e., DNA as the building block of life). Moreover, we provide a timeline to get a certain feel of the history and evolution of biotechnology, and list numerous socio-economic trends to get an idea of the importance of biotechnology in society. These trends clearly illustrate that biotechnology drives important social and economic events. Next, we evaluate biotechnology’s position in the overall technological landscape. Our main finding is that, despite its sharply increasing societal and economic importance, biotechnology still has not yet conquered a place in the technological core of our society. Reviewing the developments within synthetic biology (in this domain, complex systems are designed by (re-)combining DNA into biological parts that represent biological functions and, as such, is the domain where all aspects of biotechnology come together), it becomes clear that biotechnology as a whole is not yet in the growth stage of technological convergence that is characterized by a stable configuration of component technologies (i.e., a dominant design). Moreover, on the basis of the future expectations of experts, we conclude that biotechnology is a strategic technology that is nowhere near its peak influence, and that we can expect the importance to increase even further over the coming years. Obviously, whether biotechnology can deliver on its promise and materialize the expectations of insiders is not certain. Even when biotechnology delivers on only a small part of the promise, though, its impact will already be gigantic. For example, consider the fact that, in a 2007 interview, Craig Venter – who is one of the most well-renowned biotechnologists today – said that, in 20 years time, synthetic genomics is going to become the standard for making anything (Aldhous, 2007). So, in conclusion, biotechnology is a technology that is still emerging and does yet not display a stable and predictable pattern of growth that characterizes mature (i.e., non-emerging) technologies. Our next research question thus is as follows. Research question 2: How to study the growth of an emerging technology? In Chapter 3, on the basis of ecological insights and principles, we develop a structural or systemic view towards technology, and hereby take into explicit account the embedded nature of technology. That is, we propose that it adds value to view technology as a system composed of a set of interdependent components (or subsystems). More specifically, by relying on density dependence theory from organizational ecology, we effectively develop a multilevel framework that can be used to empirically study emerging technologies. Moreover, we employ the concept of the technological niche from organizational ecology, with its associated dimensions of crowding (associated with processes of competition) and status (associated with processes of legitimation), and add diversity as a key dimension. Through sophisticated multivariate analysis of biotechnology patents from the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO), we validate this model, which we label the ‘ecology of technology’. However, we also discover some anomalies, which point to the limitations of our model, the most important being its rather static nature. Because emerging technologies are characterized by fluid patterns of growth, a static model is a severe misrepresentation of the evolution of emerging technologies. Our next research question naturally follows from this. Research question 3: How to study the evolution of an emerging technology? On the basis of insights from evolutionary economics, Chapter 4 distinguishes between two stages of technological development, namely the stages of divergence and convergence (that connect nicely with the seed and growth stage of life cycle theory). The focal element is what is generally referred to as the deep structure (in the context of technology also commonly referred to as a dominant design) that facilitates cumulative changes by reducing uncertainty and enabling specialization and integration through standardization. The stage of divergence is characterized by the absence of a deep structure, while the stage of convergence is characterized by its presence. So, in the latter stage, there is a relatively stable configuration of the system’s component technologies that results in relatively stable and predictable patterns of growth. On the basis of these insights, we adapt our multi-level model to identify these different stages of development at the component level. More specifically, if there is a mutualistic relationship between a component and the system (i.e., if system density contributes positively to component entry), the component is argued to have a dominant design. As we are dealing with an emerging technology, our main interest lies in the transition from the initial seed stage of technological divergence (i.e., the absence of a deep structure) to a growth stage of technological convergence (i.e., the existence of a deep structure), or the creation of a deep structure. This means that we do not take into account the revolutionary transition from a stage of convergence into divergence (i.e., the maturity and decline stage in life cycle theory). Not only do we refine our predictions regarding the effects of our existing dimensions (i.e., multilevel density dependence, crowding, status, and focal diversity), but, by further taking into account the lineage of technology, we refine our dimension of diversity by adding antecedent and descendant diversity as additional dimensions to the technological niche. This results in an intricate model that can be used to study the growth and evolution of an emerging technology. We demonstrate this by an empirical investigation of biotechnology patents from the USPTO and hereby provide further support for our ‘ecology of technology’. In the light of our research objective, before we answer the question of what the precise consequences are for organizations, we ask ourselves how we can effectively integrate our findings at the organizational level of analysis. We thus formulate our next research question accordingly. Research question 4: How can we integrate technology into the theory of the organization specifictechnological niche? In Chapter 5, we use a process of logical formalization to represent the theory of the organization-specific technological niche in a formal logical language. The reason for doing so is threefold. First, this forces us to explicate all underlying assumptions and to remove any inconsistencies to make the argument logically sound. Second, this requires us to supplement the theory so that it is complete, without missing elements. Third and finally, it results in a logically sound and complete theory fragment ready for extension by integrating the insights from the study of the evolution of technology. We choose nonmonotonic logic as the language in which we represent our arguments because nonmonotonic logic is better suited for theory building, and this connects better to the current wave of formalization in non-monotonic logic in organizational ecology. On the basis of this analysis, we already make two important theoretical extensions. First, by distinguishing between crowding in technological and market space, we tie technological crowding to both competition and legitimation. To be precise, technological crowding results in competition mainly if the crowding organization is a competitor of the focal organization. Second, uncertainty mediates the relationship between the perceived and actual technological quality of the organization. More specifically, under uncertainty, the actual quality of an organization’s technology cannot be readily observed so that resource controllers have to rely on status (i.e., historic technological quality) instead. With this formalized, logically sound and complete theory fragment in hand, we can turn to the question of the organizational consequences. We thus pose our next research question as follows. Research question 5: What are the consequences of integrating several technological insights into thetheory of the organization-specific technological niche? In Chapter 6, we integrate four technological insights from Chapters 3 and 4 into our formalized theory fragment from the previous chapter. These insights are: (1) multiple technological domains exist that have (2) different stages of development, (3) different levels of uncertainty, and (4) different growth rates. On the basis of these four insights, we extend the theory of the organization-specific technological niche considerably. For crowding, we demonstrate that the effect of crowding is not only conditional upon the identity of the other organization, but also on the stage of technological development. We also add non-crowding to the mix. Regarding the effect of (non-)crowding, in the stage of divergence, multiple competing design configurations exist, and crowding (non-crowding) increases (decreases) the competitiveness of the supported design configuration, having a legitimating (competition) effect. In contrast, in the stage of convergence, crowding (non-crowding) loses its legitimating (competition) function and results in competitive (legitimation) pressure. For status, the most important consequences are that: (1) status is domain dependent, and (2) its effect is dependent upon the stage of technological development (i.e., the effect of status is higher in the stage of divergence). We also add two additional dimensions, which are (1) technological opportunities (that can be represented by the growth rate of the domain), and (2) technological diversity (measured by the distribution of activities over alternative domains). By operationalizing performance as a two-dimensional vector, we suggest that the dimensions of the technological niche are related to different performance measures in distinct temporal relationships. However, even though this theoretical extension is certainly valuable, the subsequent question is whether these extensions hold when subjected to advanced empirical tests. We therefore formulate our next research question as follows. Research question 6: Can we find proof for our extended theory of the organization-specific technological niche? In Chapter 7, we empirically test several of our theoretical extensions of the organization-specific technological niche. Our dependent variable is biotechnology innovation (i.e., the number of biotechnology patents). Through a sophisticated empirical analysis, we find strong support for our extended theory. However, we also encounter some inconsistencies and anomalies. This seems to connect to the fact that processes of competition and legitimation are more appropriately defined at lower levels of analysis (i.e., at the component instead of at the system level). Moreover, due to the dual role of a direct technological tie (i.e., it can have both a competing and a legitimating function) that forms the basis for our measure of status, status is better defined at the component level of analysis. In contrast, biotechnological quality can be aggregated to the system level without losing significance. We thus find strong support for this dimension. Furthermore, we also clearly demonstrate the importance of taking into account the different dimensions of technological diversity (i.e., antecedent, focal, and descendant), with a vital role for antecedent diversity, which logically connects with the notion of absorptive capacity. The subsequent question is what this means for the broader academic debate regarding the (co-)evolution of technology and organization. We formulate our next research question accordingly. Research question 7: What are the implications for the study of the (co-)evolution of technology and organization? In the final chapter of this dissertation, we start by stating the main contribution of this dissertation, which is that we develop a dynamic multilevel model that can be used to empirically study the evolution of an emerging technology. As this model is based on the assumption that technology can effectively be studied as a system composed of an interacting set of components, we pay explicit attention to the embedded nature of technology. Hence, when studying the evolution of technology, it is inappropriate to focus on a single level of analysis and using a multilevel perspective adds value over and above any single level study. That is, technology (e.g., biotechnology) is composed of a set of technological components (e.g., biotechnology’s component technologies) while, at the same time, being embedded in a larger technological system (i.e., technological landscape). It is precisely this multilevel nature of technology that gives it the potential to close part of the chasm in the debate between organizational adaptation (i.e., the dominant perspective in evolutionary economics) and environmental selection (i.e., the dominant perspective in organizational ecology). More specifically, by defining technology at different levels of analysis (e.g., invention, component, system, and landscape), it is possible to tie the evolution of technology to the evolution of organization at different levels of analysis (i.e., individual organization, population of organizations, community, and society). This enables studying the evolution of technology and organization in unison, and thus provides the basis for a co-evolutionary model of technology and organization. Employing a multilevel perspective to both technology and organization at the same time, and defining technology and organization as nested hierarchies tied together at multiple levels of analysis, effectively allows an analyzes of how stable configurations travels upwards in this hierarchy. After all, "it is the information about stable configurations […] that guides the process of evolution" (Simon, 1952: 473)

    In crisis geboren, 1986-1993

    No full text

    De eerste halve eeuw, 1927-1977

    No full text

    Van WHW over MUB naar BAMA, 1993-2002

    No full text

    Optimal cognitive distance and absorptive capacity

    Get PDF
    This paper tests hypotheses that in inter-firm alliances innovative performance is an inverted-U shaped function of cognitive distance, that the resulting optimal cognitive distance is higher for exploratory than for exploitative learning, and that optimal cognitive distance depends on absorptive capacity. Most hypotheses are confirmed for 994 alliances in several industries, in the period 1986-1996. The results indicate a new hypothesis that with more knowledge one needs larger cognitive distances to find novelty

    Stuurbaarheid van ganzen door verjaging en flankerende jacht rondom het ganzenopvanggebied Oost-Dongeradeel (Friesland) in 1999-2000

    Get PDF
    De stuurbaarheid van ganzen is in 1999-2000 onderzocht in een proefgebied in Noordoost-Friesland. In de periferie (ca. 9000 ha) van het ganzenopvangebied Oost-Dongeradeel (ca. 2200 ha) zijn ganzen bejaagd en verjaagd om ze te concentreren in het opvanggebied en landbouwschade in het perifere gebied te minimaliseren. Het effect van deze verjagingsacties op ganzen is bestudeerd door individueel gemerkte kolganzen intensief te volgen. Kolganzen werden hiertoe gemerkt met halsbanden en kleine, in de halsband ingebouwde, VHF-zenders. Door wekelijkse tellingen werden verspreiding en talrijkheid van alle ganzensoorten vastgelegd. De landbouwschade in het perifere gebied daalde in vergelijking met een seizoen dat er alleen gejaagd en niet gecoördineerd verjaagd werd (1997-1998), van c 350 000 naar c 150 000. Binnen het opvanggebied kwamen kolganzen meer verspreid en in kleinere groepen voor en vertoonden meer plaatstrouw. In het verjaaggebied kwamen kolganzen in veel grotere groepen voor, en doken er ook vaker nieuwe ganzen op. Ruim de helft van de ganzen trok direct door naar andere pleisterplaatsen in Nederland en Duitsland. In een gebied waar ganzen niet verjaagd werden, bleken kolganzen veel zwaarder te zijn, zodat verjagingacties zeer waarschijnlijk de conditie van ganzen beonvloeden
    corecore